How do pharmacies set prices




















The government does not fix the prices of medicines. These are set in negotiations between health insurers and pharmacists. If your pharmacist has a contract with your health insurer on providing pharmaceutical services, the bill will go directly to your health insurer.

While prescribers consider cost important in decision making for their patients, they are often inconsistent or hesitant in applying that awareness in practice. In other words, price changes will have little effect on the purchasing decision of a sick patient. The cost of doing nothing is hard to define and may not be realized for years, so even small copayment amounts on preventive treatment may be enough to deter a patient from purchasing. Influence of Supply and Supply Chain Markup.

The abundance of pharmaceutical manufacturers makes it difficult for pharmacies to purchase drug products directly from the factory where the drug is produced. The supply of pharmaceuticals involves a chain of wholesalers that help distribute drugs to pharmacies before they reach the patient.

The business model for wholesalers relies on the ability to purchase large orders of drug products from manufacturers and sell them to pharmacies at a higher price.

The pharmacies benefit from not having to coordinate with all of the manufacturers, and they enjoy reduced inventory carrying costs. This supply chain dynamic has created three transaction areas of particular interest: from manufacturer to wholesaler, from wholesaler to pharmacy, and from pharmacy to patient.

Each transaction within the chain allows for measurement of drug pricing, as displayed by the acronyms in TABLE 1. Using data collected through legally required reporting, voluntary price submissions, or other calculations allows payers to estimate the cost of drugs.

The first transaction in the supply chain between the manufacturer and wholesaler or pharmacy as a direct purchaser produces several different measurements for drug costs. The average manufacturer price AMP is a measurement of the price wholesalers pay to purchase drug products from the pharmaceutical manufacturer. The average sales price ASP is derived from the sales from manufacturers to all purchasers and includes practically all discounts, but is limited in that it is only available for Medicare Part B covered drugs.

The next transaction, between the wholesaler and the pharmacy, is another area of interest for drug cost calculation. The average wholesale price AWP is a measurement of the price paid by pharmacies to purchase drug products from wholesalers in the supply chain.

The EAC is meant to reflect the cost of the drug to the provider from the wholesaler, but is not a published figure. The average actual cost AAC is considered the final cost paid by pharmacies to their wholesalers after all discounts have been deducted and is derived from actual audits of pharmacy invoices. Currently, two states are using the AAC for pharmacy reimbursement.

The final step of the supply chain is at the retail level of distribution where the patient is the end consumer. FIGURE 1 shows a basic supply chain example from manufacturer to consumer along with some of the pricing acronyms and their relation to the supply chain. Third-Party System. In most markets, consumers see a price for a good or service and make a decision to purchase if the benefit of the good or service outweighs the cost. At the point of sale when patients pick up their prescription from the pharmacy, they usually pay a smaller portion of the transaction and the PBM reimburses the pharmacy for the balance.

This reduction in price helps drive consumer demand for this prescription medication. The PBM collects a per-prescription fee from the pharmacy whenever a consumer uses a discount program at a pharmacy.

Posted by Adam J. Fein, Ph. Without this authority, negotiation is unlikely to lead to lower prices. Three different approaches can be used to set lower prices for high-priced drugs when negotiation does not produce an agreement: i HHS could unilaterally set prices, ii HHS could establish prices through notice and comment rulemaking, or iii an independent arbitrator could set prices. Although frequently characterized as establishing negotiation, H.

The simplest, least complicated approach to setting a regulated price would empower HHS to unilaterally decide without requiring a formal process or imposing specific criteria. The Secretary would have the discretion to consider, as appropriate, the information and positions exchanged during the initial negotiation stage, as well as any expert analysis HHS might choose to consider.

HHS would have broad discretion, including whether to establish procedures for public comment by stakeholders such as manufacturers, beneficiary organizations, insurers and employers. In addition, the legislation could provide guidance to HHS, potentially limiting its discretion by specifying factors which might argue for a higher or lower price within the permitted range. To administer Medicare, HHS routinely uses notice and comment rulemaking to set prices for specific categories of hospital admissions, physician services, and those provided by many other providers.

The rule-making approach would impose procedural requirements based on the Administrative Procedures Act APA that govern how HHS exercises its decision-making authority. Formal rulemaking provides for input by multiple stakeholders and others through comments on the proposed rule, and HHS must respond to submitted comments in its final rule. Should this approach be chosen, the legislation could require publishing the proposed and final drug prices either in the Federal Register or be issued by CMS on its website, as is currently the case for the annual proposed and final payment notices for Parts C and D, involving Medicare Advantage and prescription drug plans.

To speed up the process, the public comment period could be shortened to less than the typical 60 days used for Medicare. The statute could require HHS to issue regulations establishing an overall framework, programmatic goals and decision criteria that would guide decisions and constrain how the Secretary exercises discretion. Although courts typically defer to the Executive Branch in rulemaking, the APA requires HHS to justify its proposal, limiting arbitrary and capricious actions.

In its initial notice, HHS would specify the proposed price for each designated drug along with the relevant data and analysis. In drafting the legislation, the Congress should decide whether to exempt these price decisions from judicial review, a provision adopted in past payment reform legislation that would limit the ability of manufacturers to challenge and delay implementation of the government-set prices. If legislation requires that prices be set through arbitration, it could specify who arbitrates: whether the arbitrators are federal employees or private parties, whether there is a single arbitrator or a panel, and how arbitrators are chosen.

An advantage of the latter is that it motivates both sides to submit reasonable bids, which, it is hoped, narrow the differential in proposed prices. Either way, legislation should list factors that arbitrators should consider in making their decision.

This was done in the recent legislation addressing surprise medical billing, which established a norm—median in-network payment rate in the area—and indicated what factors might be considered by arbitrators to justify a higher or lower rate. Arbitrators could be federal employees who are charged with acting independently or they could be professional non-federal arbitrators.

PRRB members are appointed by the Secretary to a three-year term, have appropriate education and professional expertise, and are subject to federal ethics rules.

Manufacturers might have concerns that, despite safeguards intended to protect their independence, federal employees would tend to favor HHS.

As a matter of public policy and accountability, objections could arise about having private individuals make decisions that are arguably inherently governmental, including determining spending by taxpayers in programs like Medicare and Medicaid.

In addition, the appearance of conflicts of interest and perceived bias might arise because private arbitration organizations, whether not-for-profit or for-profit, and the individuals they employ or contract with have an interest in securing future arbitration assignments. For example, if the federal government were to create a roster of approved arbitrators and private parties had a hand in selecting them, repeat business could be steered to arbitrators perceived as being more sympathetic to one side or the other.

Drugs differ from biologics in that the former are small molecules produced by chemical synthesis, while biologics are large, complex molecules produced by living organisms. The size and complexity of biologics typically limits the Food and Drug Administration FDA to approving biosimilars as similar but not identical to innovators , which requires a prescriber to substitute a biosimilar for a biologic.

Unlike other nations, the U. For drugs with market exclusivity and without therapeutic alternatives, the dearth of competition and the pervasiveness of insurance mean that lowering U. Examples of high-priced U. Many of the almost million annual outpatient prescriptions for brand medicines are subject to some competition from therapeutic alternatives, which are clinically similar but not chemically identical products unlike generics.

Therapeutic alternatives can range from different molecules that yield clinically similar treatments, making them broadly substitutable, to different molecules that treat the same condition but differ in clinically significant ways. Having HHS limit prices for drugs with therapeutic alternatives would substantially increase the number of medicines impacted by the price limits.

An important part of the gap between U.



0コメント

  • 1000 / 1000